ReviewEssays.com - Term Papers, Book Reports, Research Papers and College Essays
Search

Growth of Early Civilizations

Essay by   •  February 21, 2011  •  Research Paper  •  1,726 Words (7 Pages)  •  1,899 Views

Essay Preview: Growth of Early Civilizations

Report this essay
Page 1 of 7

Despite the fact that archaeology has been a long-standing area of scientific study, one of the most seemingly basic questions in the field is still unanswered: how do civilizations arise? Although the great nations of the past have left scientists clues and indicators as to their existence, history is still laden with inconsistencies and discrepancies. These irregularities have created a plethora of theories that attempt to explain how civilizations were born and how they developed. Margaret Murray, a British anthropologist who studied witch culture in Western Europe, attempts to explain the variety: "Archaeology has in it all the qualities that call for the wide view of the human race, of its growth from the savage to the civilized, which is seen in all stages of social and religious development." This "wide view" is reflected by the abundance of theories in archaeology. Looking at the various nations of the past, however, trade is a ubiquitous quality. From Mesopotamia to Mesoamerica, evidence indicates that trade was a driving influence on the specialization of labor, the division of classes, and the centralization of power in ancient times.

The two prevailing authorities on trade theories are William Rathje and Colin Renfrew. William Rathje, in his study of Mayan civilization, realized that in ancient times, Mesoamerica was a network of trading groups, in which scarce goods were able to overcome distance barriers. In his theory, Rathje identifies certain areas within these networks as the "Core Area," or the area, which consumes the majority of the resources in the region. The "Core Area" is surrounded by "Buffer Zones," regions with a multitude of resources. This system produces a centralized, trading hot-spot in which the resources are pooled to one area. As the system progresses, however, the "Buffer Zones" become more complex and autonomous. Slowly, the former "Core Area" fades out, and a number of new trade networks are born from the former "Buffer Zones." In the context of Mesoamerica, the lowlands Ð'- deficient in vital resources Ð'- needed to draw important goods from the resource-rich highlands. As trade continued, luxury goods began to pass between the regions, apparent in the presence of similar ceramics styles throughout Mexico. These transactions yielded an order in which only certain people Ð'- who, ultimately, formed the upper tier of society Ð'- could have access to the luxury goods; social stratification was a result.

Colin Renfrew's research from the Minoan Civilization on Crete contains a similar interpretation on the impact of trade. During the times of ancient Crete, demand for luxury goods, like grapes (for wine) and olives, was high, but the goods were not available on the island. As a result, the Minoan civilization established overseas trading; Crete's location in the Aegean Sea became a strategic advantage as many ships stopped through the islands' ports. Minoan influence, in fact, is present in Egypt, Mesopotamia and even Spain. This boom in trade quickly created social divisions within the society; those in control of the trading became the wealthy class of Minoan civilization. The influence of trade, however, was not only applicable to Crete; states in contact with Crete increasingly specialized in order to meet Crete's consumption habits. Renfrew's theory, like Rathje's, acknowledges that trade was a driving force behind civilizations' development.

Both Renfrew's and Rahtje's theories, however, contain fallacies that are worth mentioning. In the case of the Minoan civilization, chronology is the issue. Although scientists can agree that the domestication of grapes and olives Ð'- as a result of trade Ð'- greatly impacted the growth of Minoan society, evidence reveals that grape and olive production did not intensify until the Late Bronze Age; the rapid increase of complexity within the Minoan society, however, occurred during the Early Bronze Age, about 300 years earlier. William Rathje's argument, on the other hand, is weakened because scientists believe that the lowlands had substitutes for the scarce materials; in other words, trade was not necessary.

In Mesopotamia, however, trade was essential to the development of the area. Because the Near East is an extremely arid region, Mesopotamian states needed raw materials and resources that were not available to them locally; thus, extensive trade routes were established. During the time of the Ubaid culture (6500 Ð'- 4200 BC), trade connections with villages along the Persian Gulf were established, granting Mesopotamian states with crucial raw metals and stones. During the time of the Uruk World System (3450 Ð'- 3100 BC), trade provided timber and stone necessary for the enlargement of new cities. Archaeologists even believe that due to the high demand of raw materials, colony-like villages were settled in modern day Turkey and the Northern fringes of Mesopotamia to maintain a dependable resource base. In both examples, trade acted as a stepping-stone to the expansion of larger, complex cities. The rise of trade in Mesopotamia also necessitated more efficient and productive irrigation methods. Trade and irrigation, in fact, worked hand in hand in Mesopotamia; with more resources and better technology from abroad, states could produce more food, but as states produced more food and as the population increased, demand for foreign goods increased.

When trade is active, though, specialization of labor is compulsory, since production Ð'- and eventually, profit Ð'- is maximized. Once vital items, such as food products or raw metals begin to be traded, luxury goods enter the market, and a double-headed socioeconomic class arises: those who control and manage trade transactions, and those who can attain the luxury goods. Oftentimes, the rise of a new, upper class not only entails more social stratification, but also organized labor and an increasingly complex internal government. In the case of the Minoan civilization, the new social class of the rich was able to build elaborate palaces by organizing labor. When construction ceased, the buildings were utilized as venues for governmental meetings and administrative offices; because of trade, this state (and similar ones) were able to specialize, develop social classes, organize labor, and develop a centralized government. In Mesoamerica, on the other hand, leaders Ð'- and ultimately, social stratification

...

...

Download as:   txt (10.7 Kb)   pdf (127.8 Kb)   docx (12.8 Kb)  
Continue for 6 more pages »
Only available on ReviewEssays.com
Citation Generator

(2011, 02). Growth of Early Civilizations. ReviewEssays.com. Retrieved 02, 2011, from https://www.reviewessays.com/essay/Growth-of-Early-Civilizations/41421.html

"Growth of Early Civilizations" ReviewEssays.com. 02 2011. 2011. 02 2011 <https://www.reviewessays.com/essay/Growth-of-Early-Civilizations/41421.html>.

"Growth of Early Civilizations." ReviewEssays.com. ReviewEssays.com, 02 2011. Web. 02 2011. <https://www.reviewessays.com/essay/Growth-of-Early-Civilizations/41421.html>.

"Growth of Early Civilizations." ReviewEssays.com. 02, 2011. Accessed 02, 2011. https://www.reviewessays.com/essay/Growth-of-Early-Civilizations/41421.html.